Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

History of money

History of money

Numismatics Terminology Portal Currency

Coins, Banknotes, Forgery


Circulating currencies Community currencies

Company scrip, LETS, Time dollars


Fictional currencies Ancient currencies

Greek, Roman, China, India Byzantine


Medieval currencies Modern currencies

Africa, The Americas, Europe, Asia, Oceania


Production

Mint, Designers Coining, Milling, Hammering, Cast


Exonumia

Credit cards, Medals, Tokens, Cheques


Notaphily

Banknotes
Scripophily

Stocks, Bonds

The history of money spans thousands of years. Numismatics is the scientific study of money and its history in all its varied forms. Many items have been used as commodity money such as natural scarce precious metals, cowry shells, barley, beads etc., as well as many other things that are thought of as having value. Modern money (and most ancient money) is essentially a token in other words, an abstraction. Paper currency is perhaps the most common type of physical money today. However, objects of gold or silver present many of money's essential properties.

History of money

Non-monetary exchange: barter and gift


Contrary to popular conception, there is no evidence of a society or economy that relied primarily on barter.[1] Instead, non-monetary societies operated largely along the principles of gift economics. When barter did in fact occur, it was usually between either complete strangers or would-be enemies.[2] With barter, an individual possessing a material object of value, such as a measure of grain, could directly exchange that object for another object perceived to have equivalent value, such as a small animal, a clay pot or a tool. The capacity to carry out transactions is severely limited since it depends on a coincidence of wants. The seller of food grain has to find a buyer who wants to buy grain and who also could offer in return something the seller wants to buy. There is no common medium of exchange into which both seller and buyer could convert their tradable commodities. There is no standard which could be applied to measure the relative value of various goods and services. In a gift economy, valuable goods and services are regularly given without any explicit agreement for immediate or future rewards (i.e. there is no formal quid pro quo).[3] Ideally, simultaneous or recurring giving serves to circulate and redistribute valuables within the community. There are various social theories concerning gift economies. Some consider the gifts to be a form of reciprocal altruism. Another interpretation is that social status is awarded in return for the 'gifts'.[4] Consider for example, the sharing of food in some hunter-gatherer societies, where food-sharing is a safeguard against the failure of any individual's daily foraging. This custom may reflect altruism, it may be a form of informal insurance, or may bring with it social status or other benefits.

The emergence of money


In the absence of a medium of exchange, non-monetary societies operated largely along the principles of gift economics.[1] The Mesopotamian civilization developed a large scale economy based on commodity money. The Babylonians and their neighboring city states later developed the earliest system of economics as we think of it today, in terms of rules on debt, legal contracts and law codes relating to business practices and private property. Money was not only an emergence, it was a necessity.[5] [6] The Code of Hammurabi, the best preserved ancient law code, was created ca.1760 BC (middle chronology) in ancient Babylon. It was enacted by the sixth Babylonian king, Hammurabi. Earlier collections of laws include the code of Ur-Nammu, king of Ur (ca. 2050 BC), the Code of Eshnunna (ca. 1930 BC) and the code of Lipit-Ishtar of Isin (ca. 1870 BC).[7] These law codes formalized the role of money in civil society. They set amounts of interest on debt... fines for 'wrong doing'... and compensation in money for various infractions of formalized law. The shekel was an ancient unit of both weight and currency. It was first used in Mesopotamia around 3000 BC to define a specific weight of barley and equivalent amounts of materials such as silver, bronze and copper. The use of a single unit to define both mass and currency was a similar concept to the British pound, which was originally defined as a one pound mass of silver.

Commodity money

History of money

Bartering has several problems, most notably that it requires a 'coincidence of wants'. For example, if a wheat farmer needs what a fruit farmer produces, a direct swap is impossible as seasonal fruit would spoil before the grain harvest. A solution is to trade fruit for 1742 drawing of shells of the money cowry, wheat indirectly through a third, "intermediate", commodity: the fruit Cypraea moneta is exchanged for the intermediate commodity when the fruit ripens. If this intermediate commodity doesn't perish and is reliably in demand throughout the year (e.g. copper, gold, or wine) then it can be exchanged for wheat after the harvest. The function of the intermediate commodity as a store-of-value can be standardized into a widespread commodity money, reducing the coincidence of wants problem. By overcoming the limitations of simple barter, a commodity money makes the market in all other commodities more liquid. Many cultures around the world eventually developed the use of commodity money. Ancient China, Africa, and India used cowry shells. Trade in Japan's feudal system was based on the koku a unit of rice. The shekel was an ancient unit of weight and currency. The first usage of the term came from Mesopotamia circa 3000 BC and referred to a specific weight of barley, which related other values in a metric such as silver, bronze, copper etc. A barley/shekel was originally both a unit of currency and a unit of weight.[8] Where ever trade is common, barter systems usually lead quite rapidly to several key goods being imbued with monetary properties. In the early British colony of New South Wales, rum emerged quite soon after settlement as the most monetary of goods. When a nation is without a currency it commonly adopts a foreign currency. In prisons where conventional money is prohibited, it is quite common for cigarettes to take on a monetary quality, and throughout history, gold has taken on this unofficial monetary function.

Standardized coinage
From early times, metals, where available, have usually been favored for use as proto-money over such commodities as cattle, cowry shells, or salt, because they are at once durable, portable, and easily divisible. The use of gold as proto-money has been traced back to the fourth millennium BC when the Egyptians used gold bars of a set weight as a medium of exchange, as had been done earlier in Mesopotamia with silver bars. The first known ruler who officially set standards of weight and money was Pheidon.[9] The first stamped money (having the mark of some authority in the form of a picture or words) can be seen in the Bibliothque Nationale of Paris. It is an electrum stater of a turtle coin, coined at Aegina island. This remarkable coin[10] dates about 700 BC.[11] Electrum coins were also introduced about 650 BC in Lydia.[12]

Greek drachm of Aegina. Obverse: Land turtle / Reverse: (INA) and dolphin. The oldest turtle coin dates 700 BC

Coinage was widely adopted across Ionia and mainland Greece during the 6th century BC, eventually leading to the Athenian Empire's 5th A 640 BC one-third stater coin from Lydia, century BC, dominance of the region through their export of silver shown larger. coinage, mined in southern Attica at Laurium and Thorikos. A major silver vein discovery at Laurium in 483 BC led to the huge expansion of the Athenian military fleet. Competing coinage standards at the time were maintained by Mytilene and Phokaia using coins of Electrum; Aegina used silver. It was the discovery of the touchstone which led the way for metal-based commodity money and coinage. Any soft metal can be tested for purity on a touchstone, allowing one to quickly calculate the total content of a particular

History of money metal in a lump. Gold is a soft metal, which is also hard to come by, dense, and storable. As a result, monetary gold spread very quickly from Asia Minor, where it first gained wide usage, to the entire world. Using such a system still required several steps and mathematical calculation. The touchstone allows one to estimate the amount of gold in an alloy, which is then multiplied by the weight to find the amount of gold alone in a lump. To make this process easier, the concept of standard coinage was introduced. Coins were pre-weighed and pre-alloyed, so as long as the manufacturer was aware of the origin of A Persian 309379 AD silver drachm from the the coin, no use of the touchstone was required. Coins were typically Sasanian Dynasty. minted by governments in a carefully protected process, and then stamped with an emblem that guaranteed the weight and value of the metal. It was, however, extremely common for governments to assert that the value of such money lay in its emblem and thus to subsequently reduce the value of the currency by lowering the content of valuable metal. Although gold and silver were commonly used to mint coins, other metals could be used. For instance, Ancient Sparta minted coins from iron to discourage its citizens from engaging in foreign trade. In the early seventeenth century Sweden lacked more precious metal and so produced "plate money", which were large slabs of copper approximately 50cm or more in length and width, appropriately stamped with indications of their value. Metal based coins had the advantage of carrying their value within the coins themselves on the other hand, they induced manipulations: the clipping of coins in the attempt to get and recycle the precious metal. A greater problem was the simultaneous co-existence of gold, silver and copper coins in Europe. English and Spanish traders valued gold coins more than silver coins, as many of their neighbors did, with the effect that the English gold-based guinea coin began to rise against the English silver based crown in the 1670s and 1680s. Consequently, silver was ultimately pulled out of England for dubious amounts of gold coming into the country at a rate no other European nation would share. The effect was worsened with Asian traders not sharing the European appreciation of gold altogether gold left Asia and silver left Europe in quantities European observers like Isaac Newton, Master of the Royal Mint observed with unease.[13] Stability came into the system with national Banks guaranteeing to change money into gold at a promised rate; it did, however, not come easily. The Bank of England risked a national financial catastrophe in the 1730s when customers demanded their money be changed into gold in a moment of crisis. Eventually London's merchants saved the bank and the nation with financial guarantees. Another step in the evolution of money was the change from a coin being a unit of weight to being a unit of value. a distinction could be made between its commodity value and its specie value. The difference is these values is seigniorage.[14]

Trade bills of exchange


Bills of exchange became prevalent with the expansion of European trade toward the end of the Middle Ages. A flourishing Italian wholesale trade in cloth, woolen clothing, wine, tin and other commodities was heavily dependent on credit for its rapid expansion. Goods were supplied to a buyer against a bill of exchange, which constituted the buyer's promise to make payment at some specified future date. Provided that the buyer was reputable or the bill was endorsed by a credible guarantor, the seller could then present the bill to a merchant banker and redeem it in money at a discounted value before it actually became due. The main purpose of these bills nevertheless was, that traveling with cash was particularly dangerous at the time. a deposit could be made with a banker in one town, in turn a bill of exchange was handed out, that could be redeemed in another town. These bills could also be used as a form of payment by the seller to make additional purchases from his own suppliers. Thus, the bills an early form of credit became both a medium of exchange and a medium for storage of

History of money value. Like the loans made by the Egyptian grain banks, this trade credit became a significant source for the creation of new money. In England, bills of exchange became an important form of credit and money during last quarter of the 18th century and the first quarter of the 19th century before banknotes, checks and cash credit lines were widely available.[15]

Tallies
The acceptance of symbolic forms of money opened up vast new realms for human creativity. A symbol could be used to represent something of value that was available in physical storage somewhere else in space, such as grain in the warehouse. It could also be used to represent something of value that would be available later in time, such as a promissory note or bill of exchange, a document ordering someone to pay a certain sum of money to another on a specific date or when certain conditions have been fulfilled. In the 12th Century, the English monarchy introduced an early version of the bill of exchange in the form of a notched piece of wood known as a tally stick. Tallies originally came into use at a time when paper was rare and costly, but their use persisted until the early 19th Century, even after paper forms of money had become prevalent. The notches were used to denote various amounts of taxes payable to the crown. Initially tallies were simply used as a form of receipt to the tax payer at the time of rendering his dues. As the revenue department became more efficient, they began issuing tallies to denote a promise of the tax assessee to make future tax payments at specified times during the year. Each tally consisted of a matching pair one stick was given to the assessee at the time of assessment representing the amount of taxes to be paid later and the other held by the Treasury representing the amount of taxes be collected at a future date. The Treasury discovered that these tallies could also be used to create money. When the crown had exhausted its current resources, it could use the tally receipts representing future tax payments due to the crown as a form of payment to its own creditors, who in turn could either collect the tax revenue directly from those assessed or use the same tally to pay their own taxes to the government. The tallies could also be sold to other parties in exchange for gold or silver coin at a discount reflecting the length of time remaining until the taxes was due for payment. Thus, the tallies became an accepted medium of exchange for some types of transactions and an accepted medium for store of value. Like the girobanks before it, the Treasury soon realized that it could also issue tallies that were not backed by any specific assessment of taxes. By doing so, the Treasury created new money that was backed by public trust and confidence in the monarchy rather than by specific revenue receipts.[16]

Goldsmith bankers
Goldsmiths in England had been craftsmen, bullion merchants, money changers and money lenders since the 16th century. But they were not the first to act as financial intermediates; in the early 17th century, the scriveners were the first to keep deposits for the express purpose of relending them.[17] Merchants and traders had amassed huge hoards of gold and entrusted their wealth to the Royal Mint for storage. In 1640 King Charles I seized the private gold stored in the mint as a forced loan (which was to be paid back over time). Thereafter merchants preferred to store their gold with the goldsmiths of London, who possessed private vaults, and charged a fee for that service. In exchange for each deposit of precious metal, the goldsmiths issued receipts certifying the quantity and purity of the metal they held as a bailee (i.e. in trust). These receipts could not be assigned (only the original depositor could collect the stored goods). Gradually the goldsmiths took over the function of the scriveners of relending on behalf of a depositor and also developed modern banking practices; promissory notes were issued for money deposited which by custom and/or law was a loan to the goldsmith,[18] i.e. the depositor expressly allowed the goldsmith to use the money for any purpose including advances to his customers. The goldsmith charged no fee, or even paid interest on these deposits. Since the promissory notes were payable on demand, and the advances (loans) to the goldsmith's customers were repayable over a longer time period, this was an early from of fractional reserve banking. The promissory notes developed into an assignable instrument, which could circulate as a safe and convenient form of

History of money money backed by the goldsmith's promise to pay.[19] Hence goldsmiths could advance loans in the form of gold money, or in the form of promissory notes, or in the form of checking accounts.[20] Gold deposits were relatively stable, often remaining with the goldsmith for years on end, so there was little risk of default so long as public trust in the goldsmith's integrity and financial soundness was maintained. Thus, the goldsmiths of London became the forerunners of British banking and prominent creators of new money based on credit.

Demand deposits
The primary business of the early merchant banks was promotion of trade. The new class of commercial banks made accepting deposits and issuing loans their principal activity. They lend the money they received on deposit. They created additional money in the form of new bank notes. The money they created was partially backed by gold, silver or other assets and partially backed only by public trust in the institutions that created it. Demand deposits are funds that are deposited in bank accounts and are available for withdrawal at the discretion of the depositor. The withdrawal of funds from the account does not require contacting or making any type of prior arrangements with the bank or credit union. As long as the account balance is sufficient to cover the amount of the withdrawal, and the withdrawal takes place in accordance with procedures set in place by the financial institution, the funds may be withdrawn on demand

Banknotes
The history of money and banking are inseparably interlinked. The issuance of paper money was initiated by commercial banks. Inspired by the success of the London goldsmiths, some of which became the forerunners of great English banks, banks began issuing paper notes quite properly termed banknotes which circulated in the same way that government issued currency circulates today. In England this practice continued up to 1694. Scottish banks continued issuing notes until 1850. In USA, this practice continued through the 19th Century, where at one time there were more than 5000 different types of bank notes issued by various commercial banks in America. Only the notes issued by the largest, most creditworthy banks were widely accepted. The script of smaller, lesser known institutions circulated locally. Farther from home it was only accepted at a discounted rate, if it was accepted at all. The proliferation of types of money went hand in hand with a multiplication in the number of financial institutions. These banknotes were a form of representative money which could be converted into gold or silver by application at the bank. Since banks issued notes far in excess of the gold and silver they kept on deposit, sudden loss of public confidence in a bank could precipitate mass redemption of banknotes and result in bankruptcy. The use of bank notes issued by private commercial banks as legal tender has gradually been replaced by the issuance of bank notes authorized and controlled by national governments. The Bank of England was granted sole rights to issue banknotes in England after 1694. In the USA, the Federal Reserve Bank was granted similar rights after its establishment in 1913. Until recently, these government-authorized currencies were forms of representative money, since they were partially backed by gold or silver and were theoretically convertible into gold or silver.

Gold-backed banknotes
The term gold standard is often erroneously thought to refer to a currency where notes were fully backed by and redeemable in an equivalent amount of gold. The British pound was the strongest, most stable currency of the 19th Century and often considered the closest equivalent to pure gold, yet at the height of the gold standard there was only sufficient gold in the British treasury to redeem a small fraction of the currency then in circulation. In 1880, US government gold stock was equivalent in value to only 16% of currency and demand deposits in commercial banks. By 1970, it was about 0.5%. The gold standard was only a system for exchange of value between national currencies, never an agreement to redeem all paper notes for gold. The classic gold standard prevailed during the period 1880 and 1913 when a core of leading trading nations agreed to adhere to a fixed gold price and continuous convertibility

History of money for their currencies. Gold was used to settle accounts between these nations. With the outbreak of World War I, Britain was forced to abandon the gold standard even for their international transactions. Other nations quickly followed suit. After a brief attempt to revive the gold standard during the 1920s, it was finally abandoned by Britain and other leading nations during the Great Depression. Prior to the abolition of the gold standard, the following words were printed on the face of every US dollar: "I promise to pay the bearer on demand, the sum of one dollar" followed by the signature of the US Secretary of the Treasury. Other denominations carried similar pledges proportionate to the face value of each note. The currencies of other nations bore similar promises too. In earlier times this promise signified that a bearer could redeem currency notes for their equivalent value in gold or silver. The US adopted a silver standard in 1785, meaning that the value of the US dollar represented a certain equivalent weight in silver and could be redeemed in silver coins. But even at its inception, the US Government was not required to maintain silver reserves sufficient to redeem all the notes that it issued. Through much of the 20th Century until 1971, the US dollar was backed by gold, but from 1934 only foreign holders of the notes could exchange them for metal.

Fiat money
Fiat money refers to money that is not backed by reserves of another commodity. The money itself is given value by government fiat (Latin for "let it be done") or decree, enforcing legal tender laws, previously known as "forced tender", whereby debtors are legally relieved of the debt if they pay it in the government's money. By law, the refusal of a legal tender (offering) extinguishes the debt in the same way acceptance does.[21] At times in history (e.g. Rome under Diocletian, and post-revolutionary France during the collapse of the assignats) the refusal of legal tender money in favor of some other form of payment was punished with the death penalty. Governments through history have often switched to forms of fiat money in times of need such as war, sometimes by suspending the service they provided of exchanging their money for gold, and other times by simply printing the money that they needed. When governments produce money more rapidly than economic growth, the money supply overtakes economic value. Therefore, the excess money eventually dilutes the market value of all money issued. This is called inflation. See open market operations. In 1971 the United States finally switched to fiat money indefinitely. At this point in time many of the economically developed countries' currencies were fixed to the US dollar (see Bretton Woods Conference), and so this single step meant that much of the western world's currencies became fiat money based. Following the Gulf War the president of Iraq, Saddam Hussein, repealed the existing Iraqi fiat currency and replaced it with a new currency. Despite having no backing by a commodity and with no central authority mandating its use or defending its value, the old currency continued to circulate within the politically isolated Kurdish regions of Iraq. It became known as the "Swiss dinar". This currency remained relatively strong and stable for over a decade. It was formally replaced following the Iraq War.

References
[1] Mauss, Marcel. 'The Gift: The Form and Reason for Exchange in Archaic Societies.' pp. 3637. [2] David Graeber (2001). Toward an anthropological theory of value: the false coin of our own dreams (http:/ / books. google. com/ books?id=uo8tttilAlQC& pg=PA153). Palgrave Macmillan. pp.153154. ISBN9780312240455. . Retrieved 10 February 2011. [3] Cheal, David J (1988). "1" (http:/ / books. google. com/ books?id=o-wNAAAAQAAJ& pg=PP1). The Gift Economy. New York: Routledge. pp.119. ISBN0415006414. . Retrieved 2009-06-18. [4] Gifford Pinchot The Gift Economy (http:/ / www. context. org/ ICLIB/ IC41/ PinchotG. htm). Context.org (2000-06-29). Retrieved on 2011-02-10. [5] Sheila C. Dow (2005), " Axioms and Babylonian thought: a reply (http:/ / ideas. repec. org/ a/ mes/ postke/ v27y2005i3p385-391. html)", Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 27 (3), p. 385-391. [6] The Reforms of Urukagina (http:/ / history-world. org/ reforms_of_urukagina. htm). History-world.org. Retrieved on 2011-02-10. [7] Charles F. Horne (1915). "The Code of Hammurabi : Introduction" (http:/ / www. yale. edu/ lawweb/ avalon/ medieval/ hammint. htm). Yale University. . Retrieved September 14, 2007.

History of money
[8] Kramer, History Begins at Sumer, pp. 5255. [9] Full text of "The earliest coins of Greece proper" (http:/ / www. archive. org/ stream/ earliestcoinsofg00garduoft/ earliestcoinsofg00garduoft_djvu. txt). Archive.org. Retrieved on 2011-02-10. [10] Coin images (http:/ / www. snible. org/ coins/ bmc/ attica/ XXIII. jpg) [11] Ancient coinage of Aegina (http:/ / www. snible. org/ coins/ hn/ aegina. html). Snible.org. Retrieved on 2011-02-10. [12] Goldsborough, Reid. "World's First Coin" (http:/ / rg. ancients. info/ lion/ article. html) [13] "Sir Isaac Newton's state of the gold and silver coin (25 September 1717)." (http:/ / www. pierre-marteau. com/ editions/ 1701-25-mint-reports/ report-1717-09-25. html). Pierre Marteau. . [14] "Mineral Profiles" (http:/ / pubs. usgs. gov/ of/ 2002/ of02-303/ OFR_02-303. pdf) (PDF). U.S. Geological Survey. . [15] Davies, Glyn, A History of Money (http:/ / projects. exeter. ac. uk/ RDavies/ arian/ llyfr. html), University of Wales, 1994, p.172, 339. ISBN 0708317170 [16] Davies, Glyn, A History of Money (http:/ / projects. exeter. ac. uk/ RDavies/ arian/ llyfr. html), University of Wales, 1994, pp. 146151 ISBN 0708317170 [17] Richards [18] Thus by the 19th century we find [i]n ordinary cases of deposits of money with banking corporations, or bankers, the transaction amounts to a mere loan or mutuum, and the bank is to restore, not the same money, but an equivalent sum, whenever it is demanded. Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Law of Bailments (1832, p. 66) and Money, when paid into a bank, ceases altogether to be the money of the principal (see Parker v. Marchant, 1 Phillips 360); it is then the money of the banker, who is bound to return an equivalent by paying a similar sum to that deposited with him when he is asked for it. Lord Chancellor Cottenham, Foley v Hill (1848) 2 HLC 28. [19] Richards. The usual denomination was 50 or 100 pounds, so these notes were not an everyday currency for the common people. [20] Richards, p. 40 [21] "Fiat money." (http:/ / www. encyclopedia. com/ topic/ fiat_money. aspx) The Columbia Encyclopedia, Sixth Edition. 2008. Encyclopedia.com. Retrieved July-17-09

Bibliography
Richards, R. D. Early history of banking in England. London: R. S. King, 1929.

Further reading
Jevons, W. S. (1875), Money and the Mechanism of Exchange, London: Macmillan. Menger, Carl, "On the Origin of Money" (http://socserv.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/menger/money.txt) Szabo, Nick, Shelling Out The Origins of Money (http://szabo.best.vwh.net/shell.html)

External links
The Marteau Early 18th-Century Currency Converter (http://www.pierre-marteau.com/currency/converter. html) A Platform of Research in Economic History. Linguistic and Commodity Exchanges (http://www.egwald.ca/ubcstudent/aboriginal/exchanges.php) by Elmer G. Wiens. Examines the structural differences between barter and monetary commodity exchanges and oral and written linguistic exchanges. Historical Currency Conversion Page (http://www.history.ucsb.edu/faculty/marcuse/projects/currency.htm) by Harold Marcuse. Focuses on converting German marks to US dollars since 1871 and inflating them to values today, but has much additional information on the history of currency exchange. History of Money (https://www.crazy4moneyclips.com/money-clip-facts.aspx). By Bill Wilson. Quick and easy to understand history of money and the items in which it is carried.

Article Sources and Contributors

Article Sources and Contributors


History of money Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?oldid=465378924 Contributors: A poor workman blames, A876, Aaronstewart, Acad Ronin, Ajraddatz, Aka042, Aldux, Aleenf1, Andrew c, Anna Lincoln, Anthony Appleyard, Apaton, Arthur Rubin, Ashanda, Baronnet, Beano, Benjo71, Benny the wayfarer, Bobby131313, Bogey97, Bonadea, Bosporos, Buddy23Lee, Bunchofgrapes, Capricorn42, CardinalDan, Carl.bunderson, Carlomorino, Carnivorios, Carolmooredc, Caster23, Chase me ladies, I'm the Cavalry, Chochopk, ChrisCork, Codyryanharrod, Colfulus, Colonies Chris, CommonsDelinker, Courcelles, Cretog8, CronopioFlotante, Crosbiesmith, DARTH SIDIOUS 2, DVD R W, DVD Smith, Daniel J. Petrie, Darkx3000, Davecrosby uk, DeltaQuad, DerHexer, Deslie, Dgies, Doramjan, E4mmacro, Eastlaw, Epafus, Epbr123, Favonian, Fibula, Finn Bjrklid, Fortdj33, Four Seven Nine, Funandtrvl, GTBacchus, Gaius Cornelius, Galapagosa, Gilliam, GraemeL, Gscshoyru, Gwernol, Heron, HexaChord, Hires an editor, Hmarcuse, Htfiddler, ImperfectlyInformed, Invertzoo, Iridescent, Isenburger, J.delanoy, Jason Hommel, Jeff3000, Jhenderson777, Jimtpat, Jkl, Jnc, John D. Croft, John Hill, Jolis, KHirsch, KennethJ, Krj373, Kroketa, Kukini, Kusunose, KymeSnake, Lawrencekhoo, Lcarscad, LeaveSleaves, Levelcopy, Logan, Loudsox, Lunchscale, MER-C, Martial75, Materialscientist, Matthew9876, Mauler90, MissAlyx, Mom2jandk, Mr. Billion, Najro, Nard the Bard, Nathanael Bar-Aur L., NawlinWiki, Novacatz, Octothorn, Officialpages, Ohnoitsjamie, Olaf Simons, Oracleofottawa, OwenX, Oxymoron83, PJBEAR13, PatClay, Patsw, Pharaoh of the Wizards, Philip Trueman, Pill, Pinethicket, Pingveno, Pizzadude.ca, Protomoney, Psjalltheway, Puchiko, Quadell, Qwasty, RA0808, Radagast83, Raven in Orbit, Recury, Renaissance Man, Rich Farmbrough, Rintrah, Rjwilmsi, Ronbo76, Rosser1954, S Marshall, Sasanjan, Searchme, Shae, Simplicius, Skipsievert, Smooth08, Snowolf, StAnselm, SteinbDJ, Stevenmitchell, SueHay, Tail, Tdadamemd, Terjepetersen, TerraHikaru, Thatguyflint, The wub, Theropod, Tiddly Tom, Tide rolls, Timrem, Timrollpickering, Tirolion, Tommy2010, Tonyrex, Tortor, Treisijs, TruthSeeker1234, Tungngm, Tyw7, Van der Hoorn, Vrenator, Wetman, WittyMan1986, Womzilla, Woohookitty, Wragge, Xicsies, YK Times, Yopie, Yworo, Zealander, Zinger0, Zoeperkoe, Zsniew, , 362 anonymous edits

Image Sources, Licenses and Contributors


Image:Claudius II coin (colourised).png Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Claudius_II_coin_(colourised).png License: Public Domain Contributors: Ssolbergj Image:Portal-puzzle.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Portal-puzzle.svg License: Public Domain Contributors: Anomie Image:Cypraea-moneta-001.jpg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Cypraea-moneta-001.jpg License: Public Domain Contributors: Niccol Gualtieri Image:BMC 193.jpg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:BMC_193.jpg License: GNU Free Documentation License Contributors: Alfons berg, Bibi Saint-Pol, Carlomorino, Jastrow, Paradoctor Image:BMC 06.jpg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:BMC_06.jpg License: GNU Free Documentation License Contributors: Alfons berg, Carlomorino, Jastrow, Paradoctor, Schimmelreiter, Sumerophile, Thuresson, Xhienne, 1 anonymous edits Image:Shapuri.jpg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Shapuri.jpg License: GNU Free Documentation License Contributors: Jastrow, Udimu, ZxxZxxZ

License
Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported //creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/

You might also like